Discussion about this post

User's avatar
Opus 6's avatar

Thanks for the explanation of how the current system works.

The definition of “subsidy” is rather important here, isn’t it? I think what many people mean when they say that social housing is subsidised is that they are paying taxes that are going directly into the pockets of tenants. For example, the “zoomer” who wrote an article on Matt Goodwin‘s Substack complains that he is paying council tax to enable other people to live in social housing. The council that did this would, of course, be breaking the law. You acknowledge that in the past, social housing tenants have paid the costs of maintaining their properties through their rents. So there is no direct financial subsidy in this case.

You say that the cost of maintaining the social housing stock has risen because of new energy efficiency rules etc. and that in the future, maintaining the properties might only be possible with increased government funding. This would indeed be a financial subsidy.

If the state decides it doesn’t want to pay this subsidy, the obvious thing to do would be to increase rents. However, this then raises the question of what to do with those tenants who cannot afford the higher rents. There will be little point in kicking them out if they end up renting privately and claiming housing benefit.

I find the section on housing benefit puzzling. Yes, housing benefit is a direct financial subsidy. But housing benefit is paid both to social tenants and to private tenants. I’m not sure how it is relevant to the question of whether social housing per se is subsidised.

So what is a “subsidy”? You say:

“The decision to rent properties out at anything less than market rates is a subsidy.”

Is it?

An alternative definition would be that a subsidy is a payment made in order to allow something to be sold at less than the cost of production. For consumer goods such as cars and televisions produced in a competitive market, the market rate and the cost of production should be approximately equal. The market rate in the private rental market, however, is not determined by the cost of production i.e. by the cost of building and maintaining the property. That’s because the market rate includes a payment made for the land underneath the property i.e. for the property’s location. The land costs nothing to produce and yet it commands a price because the landlord controls access to it.

So even a social tenant who pays the full costs of building and maintaining her property will pay less than the market rate in the private rental market because she does not have to pay for the land. Such a tenant does not require any financial subsidy from the taxpayer despite being better off than a tenant renting an equivalent property in the private sector.

You say, however, that “even if social housing might be self-financing on a financial (i.e., money in/money out) basis (ignoring the role of Housing Benefit), it certainly isn’t on an economic basis.” You say that the state is incurring an opportunity cost by not renting out the property it owns at the market rate.

This is obviously true, but what is puzzling is why you seem to think that this applies only to people occupying social housing. The state could, if it wished, arrogate all the land rents in London to itself by imposing a 100% Land Value Tax. It chooses not to do so. So yes, the state incurs an opportunity cost by not collecting land rents from social housing tenants, but it also incurs an opportunity cost by not collecting land rents from landlords and owner occupiers. What’s the difference? (To say that the difference is that landlords and owner occupiers “own” their land would be begging the question.)

You say that constructing social housing produces “severe economic distortion, preventing the market from channeling resources to wherever they are most needed”. The implication is that the most efficient allocation of housing will occur if all housing is privately owned and is bought, sold and rented in the marketplace. But this is false because when a commodity - in this case, land - is fixed in supply, people will hoard it. Elderly people, for example, will continue to live in large houses in sought-after locations because they know that those houses will increase in value. If you really want land to be used in the most efficient way, you need to nationalise land rents and force everybody – not just social tenants - to pay for the land they use. Then you have a genuine free market.

Expand full comment
1 more comment...

No posts